Bastiat on “The seen and the unseen”
In the economic sphere an act, a habit, an institution, a law produces not only one effect, but a series of effects. Of these effects, the first alone is immediate; it appears simultaneously with its cause; it is seen. The other effects emerge only subsequently; they are not seen; we are fortunate if we foresee them.There is only one difference between a bad economist and a good one: the bad economist confines himself to the visible effect; the good economist takes into account both the effect that can be seen and those effects that must be foreseen.Yet this difference is tremendous; for it almost always happens that when the immediate consequence is favorable, the later consequences are disastrous, and vice versa. Whence it follows that the bad economist pursues a small present good that will be followed by a great evil to come, while the good economist pursues a great good to come, at the risk of a small present evil.Frederic Bastiat, Selected Essays On Political Economy 1848
Henry Hazlitt explains:
A certain amount of public spending is necessary toperform essential government functions. A certain amountof public works of streets and roads and bridges andtunnels, of armories and navy yards, of buildings tohouse legislatures, police and fire departments-is neces-sary to supply essential public services, With such publicworks, necessary for their own sake, and defended on thatground alone, l am not here concerned. I am here con-cerned with public works considered as a means of “pro-viding employment” or of adding wealth to the com-munity that it would not otherwise have had.A bridge is built. If it is built to meet an insistentpublic demand, if it solves a traffic problem or a trans-portation problem otherwise insoluble, if, in short, it iseven more necessary than the things for which the tax~payers would have spent their money if it had not beentaxed away from them, there can be no objection. Buta bridge built primarily “to provide employment” is adifferent kind of bridge. When providing employment be-comes the end, need becomes a subordinate consideration.“Projects” have to be invented. Instead of thinking onlywhere bridges must be built, the government spendersbegin to ask themselves where bridges can be built. Canthey think of plausible reasons why an additional bridgeshould connect Easton and Weston? lt soon becomes ab-solutely essential. Those who doubt the necessity aredismissed as obstructionists and reactionaries.Two arguments are put forward for the bridge, oneof which is mainly heard before it is built, the other ofwhich is mainly heard after it has been completed. Thefirst argument is that it will provide employment. It willprovide, say, 500 jobs for a year. The implication is thatthese are jobs that would not otherwise have come intoexistence.This is what is immediately seen. But if we have trainedourselves to look beyond immediate to secondary conse-quences, and beyond those who are directly benefited by agovernment project to others who are indirectly affected,a different picture presents itself. It is true that a par-ticular group of bridgeworkers may receive more em-ployment than otherwise. But the bridge has to be paidfor out of taxes. For every dollar that is spent on thebridge a dollar will be taken away from taxpayers. If thebridge costs $1,000,000 the taxpayers will lose $1,000,000.They will have that much taken away from themwhich they would otherwise have spent on the thingsthey needed most.Therefore for every public job created by the bridgeproject a private job has been destroyed somewhere else.We can see the men employed on the bridge. We canwatch them at work. The employment argument of thegovernment spenders becomes vivid, and probably formost people convincing. But there are other things thatwe do not see, because, alas, they have never been permitted to come into existence. They are the jobs destroyedby the $1,000,000 taken from the taxpayers. All that hashappened, at best, is that there has been a diversion ofjobs because of the project. More bridge builders; fewerautomobile workers, radio technicians, clothing workers,farmers.– But then we come to the second argument. The bridgeexists. lt is, let us suppose, a beautiful and not an uglybridge. It has come into being through the magic of gov-ernrnent spending. Where would it have been if the ob-structionists and the reactionaries had had their way?There would have been no bridge. The country wouldhave been just that much poorer.Here again the government spenders have the better ofthe argument with all those who cannot see beyond theimmediate range of their physical eyes. They can see thebridge. But if they have taught themselves to look forindirect as well as direct consequences they can oncemore see in the eye of imagination the possibilities thathave never been allowed to come into existence. Theycan see the unbuilt homes, the unmade cars and radios,the unmade dresses and coats, perhaps the unsold andungrown foodstuffs. To see these uncreated things re-quires a kind of imagination that not many people have.We can think of these non-existent objects once, perhaps,but we cannot keep them before our minds as we can thebridge that we pass every working day. What has hap-pened is merely that one thing bas been created insteadof others.The same reasoning applies, of course, to every otherform of public work. It applies just as well, for example,to the erection with public funds of housing for peopleof low incomes, All that happens is that money is takenaway through taxes from families of higher income (andperhaps a little from families of even lower income) toforce them to subsidize these selected families with lowincomes and enable them to live in better housing for thesame rent or for lower rent than previously.I do not intend to enter here into all the pros and consof public housing. I am concerned only to point out theerror in two of the arguments most frequently put for-ward in favor of public housing. One is the argumentthat it “creates employment”; the other that it createswealth which would not otherwise have been produced.Both of these arguments are false, because they overlookwhat is lost through taxation. Taxation for public housingdestroys as many jobs in other lines as it creates inhousing. It also results in unbuilt private homes, in un-made washing machines and refrigerators, and in lack ofinnumerable other commodities and services.And none of this is answered by the sort of reply whichpoints out, for example, that public housing does not haveto be financed by a lump sum capital appropriation, butmerely by annual rent subsidies. This simply means thatthe cost is spread over many years instead of being con-centrated in one. It also means that what is taken fromthe taxpayers is spread over many years instead of beingconcentrated into one. Such technicalities are irrelevantto the main point.The great psychological advantage of the public hous-ing advocates is that men are seen at work on the houseswhen they are going up, and the houses are seen whenthey are finished. People live in them, and proudly showtheir friends through the rooms. The jobs destroyed bythe taxes for the housing are not seen, nor are the goodsand services that were never made. It takes a concentratedeffort of thought, and a new effort each time the housesand the happy people in them are seen, to think of thewealth that was not created instead. Is it surprising thatthe champions of public housing should dismiss this, ifit is brought to their attention, as a world of imagination,as the objections of pure theory, while they point to thepublic housing that exists? As a character in BernardShaw’s Saint Joan replies when told of the theory ofPythagoras that the earth is round and revolves aroundthe sun: “What an utter fool! Couldn’t he use his eyes?”Henry Hazlitt, Economics In One Lesson 1946.
Please remember this when you see our new street lights, sidewalks, and especially the new 9th Ave Pier.
.
Post a Comment